I. Introduction
China’s President Xi, in the 19th National People’s Congress of the Communist Party of China, announced that China had turned to a stage of high-quality development (HQD). That is, HQD had become a crucial guiding ideology in the future economic development and social construction in China. Therefore, how to achieve the old and new kinetic energy transformation and promote HQD is a heated topic in current economic studies. However, the negative externalities imposed by the traditional extensive economic development pattern have triggered imbalances such as environmental deterioration in China’s socioeconomic development (Hong et al., 2022). It is undeniable that energy plays a crucial role in improving people’s wellbeing (Li & Lin, 2017). To some extent, China’s rapid economic growth was driven by massive energy consumption (Zhu et al., 2019). Specifically, China’s total energy consumption has increased from 5.714 million tons of standard coal in 1978 to 4.98 billion tons of standard coal in 2020 (National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2021).[1] Meanwhile, China is also the world’s largest energy consumer and CO2 emitter (Wu, Ren, et al., 2020). To this end, facing severe environmental issues and energy scarcity, China must adapt its economic development model and introduce feasible policies that are in line with inclusive development.
Environmental governance can be considered as an effective instrument in enhancing energy efficiency and addressing negative externalities of environmental pollution (Costantini & Crespi, 2008; Sun et al., 2019). China has successively enacted several energy saving and emission alleviation policies such as The Energy Development Strategic Action Plan. In the meantime, the share of fiscal expenditure for energy conservation and environmental protection has dramatically increased from 2% in 2007 to 4% in 2020. Additionally, China also marked great achievements in environmental policy innovations from the institutional perspective, highlighting the re-articulation of the existing environmental regulation system, the execution of the local government’s ecological duty and social inclusive development (Li & Lin, 2019). The essence of lies in authorities’ allocation of environmental protection affairs among different levels of government, namely, environmental decentralization.
Empirical findings have suggested that (Song et al., 2022) or technological progress (Song et al., 2022), which explicitly implies nonlinearity between and Adopting China’s 30 provinces from 2005 to 2016, we validate the potential non-linear effect of on by implementing the Panel Smooth Transition Regression (PSTR) model.
can affect eco-friendly efficiency through labour productivity improvementThe remainder of this paper is organised as follows: Section II describes the methodology. Section III reports the empirical findings. Section IV concludes this study.
II. Methodology
First, (2015) and Li & Lin (2017), we take bad output into full account to measure adopting Super-SBM model. Specifically, capital, labour, and total energy consumption are selected as input factors. The expected output is GDP. Wastewater discharge, solid waste generation and exhaust gas emission are treated as bad outputs.
is defined as the proportion of theoretical minimum factor inputs to the actual input levels when the bad output is minimised under a bundle of good outputs. Following Zhang et al.Second, three indicators (namely, wastewater compliance rate, SO2 removal rate and industrial solid waste comprehensive utilization rate) are applied to establish a performance-based (Wu, Xu, et al., 2020). Specifically, the adjusted coefficient is:
index systemRij=ℜij∑iℜij/RGDPi∑iRGDPi
where
denotes the discharge of the pollutant of the province, which is normalised using and are minimum and maximum values of represents the real GDP in province If the emission of pollutant in the th province is high, then the same pollution rate indicates stronger and the weight assigned would be higher. Using the normalised values and is calculated as follows:ER=3∑j=113R′ij∗Rij
We improve the model developed by Nasreen & Anwar (2014) by incorporating other macro factors.
EFEit= αiERit+α′itERit⋅I(Tit−1;γ,ϑ)+ϑjxj,it+ϑ′jxj,it⋅I(Tit−1;γ,ϑ)+μi+εit
where Ullah et al., 2021). suggests a linear relationship (Regime 1), while indicates a non-linear relationship (Regime 2). Exogeneous variables or a combination of lagged endogenous variables can be treated as a threshold indicator (Lee & Chiu, 2011, 2012). The lagged explanatory variable is treated as a threshold indicator denotes the selected control variables, namely, foreign direct investment (fdi), infrastructure (if), economic growth (pgdp), industrial structure (is), and R&D input (ri). All variables have been transformed into the natural logarithms.
denotes individual fixed effect; is the error term; represents a transition function of the threshold indicator which is continuous and bounded between 0 and 1 (seeFollowing Colletaz et al. (2006), we consider the following transition function of logistic specification:
I(Tit−1;γ,ϑ)= [1+exp(−γm∏j=1(Tit−1−ϑj)]−1,γ>0,ϑ1≤…≤ϑm
where
represents an m-dimensional vector of location parameters; coefficient captures the smoothness of transition. The model collapses into linear regression model with fixed effect, assuming Thus, PSTR model with multiple regimes is specified asEFEit= αiERit+q∑i=1α′itERit⋅Ij(Tjit−1;γj,ϑj)+ϑjxj,it+q∑i=1ϑ′ijxj,it⋅Ij(Tjit−1;γ,ϑ)+μi+εit.
Transition functions
depend on the slope coefficients and location coefficients If and for all is assumed as an indicator function. Equation (5) is a panel transition regression model with regimes. Thus, ’s elasticity coefficient (EC) on EEF for province at year is given as:eERit=∂EEFit∂ERit=αi+q∑j=1α′itIj(Tjit−1;γj,ϑj)
where
is the estimated EEF improvement (or degeneration) in terms of varies both over year and across provinces. Parameters and regulate the ECs of linear and nonlinear models, respectively.The PSTR model proposed by Gonzalez et al. (2004) allows for a small number of extreme regimes linked to the extreme value of a transaction function. Also, it allows for a continuum: each one is characterised by a different value of the transition function. In our context, the PSTR allows cross-provincial heterogeneity and time instability of the elasticities without configuration of ex-ante classification over individuals. It is therefore suitable to adopt the PSTR model to capture the possible nonlinearity between and
All monetary indicators have been converted into 2005 constant price. The data is mainly collected from China Environmental Statistics Yearbook, China Energy Statistics Yearbook, China Science and Technology Yearbook, and National Bureau of Statistics of China.
III. Findings
First, we check whether (Colletaz et al., 2006). Results reported in Panel A of Table 1 rejects the null hypothesis at a 1% significance level, highlighting that has a nonlinear effect on
has a non-linear effect onSecond, the remaining non-linearity test[2] is applied to verify whether the model is adequately estimated and then determines the number of transition functions. Specifically, the model is considered as reasonable if the null hypothesis is supported. Conversely, if the null hypothesis is rejected, then the model may contain multiple transition functions. Panel B of Table 2 displays that Equation (5) has been iteratively examined and the null hypothesis has been accepted until implying that Equation (5) converges to three-regime PSTR model.
Third, Table 2 displays that there are two structural breakpoints for the - nexus. Specifically, a dramatic change between Regimes 1 and 2, because of the high value. At this point, the transition function tends to be an indicator function. The transition from Regime 2 to 3 shows a sharp decline, with a difference of 3.2428. The regression results also show that if is lower than -1.2409, EC is -1.1587 and such an effect is statistically significant. If is more than -1.2409 but less than -0.1124, EC is -1.0713, while if exceeds -0.1124, EC converges to -1.0827.
The above estimated results imply that stringent (Saidi & Hammami, 2015). Besides, the compliance cost of will reduce firm’s profits. It would be virtually impossible to encourage firms to carry out technological research, and this would hinder in the short term (Esso & Keho, 2016). As a result, firms have to re-structure their production layout and update their production techniques, and ultimately improve (Peuckert, 2014). On the other hand, China Environmental Protection Tax Law pays less attention to consumption-based environmental responsibility. According to Xue et al. (2022), the configuration of China’s current tax rates is not optimal, which mainly reflects that inter-provincial trade activities lead to cross-border pollution emission transfer that brings a burden on provinces with low tax rates. Consequently, pollution emissions generated from the developed and coastal provinces will be transferred to the developing and interior provinces. Moreover, tax revenue obtained from related policies will be fed back to the economy to maintain government revenue. For example, revenues from specific taxes will be applied to compensate for the revenue loss from the reduction of corporate and personal income taxes and offer lump-sum transfers to those low-income groups (Yamazaki, 2022). Therefore, in the long-term, the willingness of firms to pursue technological innovation and emission reduction may decrease, thereby hindering
could inhibit enhancement, while the influential magnitude has exhibited an ‘‘V-shaped’’ trend. More specifically, even before reaches its turning point, an enhancement in will inhibit improvement. The inhibitory effect shows a decreasing trend after strengthening by a certain degree. Unfortunately, further improvement in will once again curb in the long run. This should be attributed to the following explanations. On the one hand, when degree is low, payment costs of environmental deterioration is triggered by account for a small share of firms’ total cost. Thus, firms lack the motivation to conduct R&D activities to achieve a ‘‘win-win’’ situation of energy conservation and pollution reductionIV. Conclusion
Our findings reflect the existence of a strongly nonlinear relationship between
and has inhibited in China. The inhibitory effect first decreases and shows an upward trend with further improvement in and, thus, forming a ‘‘V-shaped’’ trend. Thus, we recommend that: (1) China should carefully design scientific and stringent environmental policies that are in line with regional and national realities. This would trigger the ‘‘Porter Effect’’ and strengthen the independent innovative capability of firms, thereby ultimately improving (2) China streamlines administration in and give full play to the decisive role of the market in resource allocation; (3) Relevant authorities should actively refine the China’s negative list for market access.The remaining non-linearity test is carried out with
alternative hypotheses.